WEBVTT 1 00:00:00.660 --> 00:00:01.493 Hey, everyone, 2 00:00:01.493 --> 00:00:03.210 and welcome back to Module Two. 3 00:00:03.210 --> 00:00:05.250 In this lecture, I'll be presenting an overview 4 00:00:05.250 --> 00:00:08.013 of healthcare systems, financing, and payments. 5 00:00:08.880 --> 00:00:11.779 In this lecture, we're going to be discussing global 6 00:00:11.779 --> 00:00:14.040 and national health expenditures, health system financing, 7 00:00:14.040 --> 00:00:17.730 healthcare delivery models, and provider payment mechanisms. 8 00:00:17.730 --> 00:00:19.260 One reason why it is important 9 00:00:19.260 --> 00:00:21.060 to discuss health systems financing 10 00:00:21.060 --> 00:00:22.530 is that there is a wide variation 11 00:00:22.530 --> 00:00:25.233 in the amount of gross domestic product, or GDP, 12 00:00:26.250 --> 00:00:29.733 spent on health systems on average between countries. 13 00:00:31.650 --> 00:00:34.390 And there's also variation between the structure 14 00:00:36.120 --> 00:00:38.493 of these expenditures between countries. 15 00:00:39.690 --> 00:00:41.640 So to begin with, health system financing 16 00:00:41.640 --> 00:00:44.010 is defined as the process of collecting, allocating, 17 00:00:44.010 --> 00:00:46.620 and distributing revenues to cover health services 18 00:00:46.620 --> 00:00:48.690 for a designated population. 19 00:00:48.690 --> 00:00:51.202 Every country is different, and moreover, 20 00:00:51.202 --> 00:00:53.310 experiences demographic changes 21 00:00:53.310 --> 00:00:54.900 in epidemiological transitions 22 00:00:54.900 --> 00:00:57.180 that influence the population's healthcare needs 23 00:00:57.180 --> 00:01:00.330 and the demand for specific healthcare services. 24 00:01:00.330 --> 00:01:02.280 Consequently, health financing policy 25 00:01:02.280 --> 00:01:05.730 cannot be imported from one com country to another. 26 00:01:05.730 --> 00:01:08.160 Healthcare systems raise revenues for the health system 27 00:01:08.160 --> 00:01:09.483 from a variety of sources. 28 00:01:10.530 --> 00:01:12.600 It is important to ensure that the flow of these funds 29 00:01:12.600 --> 00:01:14.400 is stable and predictable. 30 00:01:14.400 --> 00:01:16.553 Examples of strategies for raising revenue 31 00:01:16.553 --> 00:01:20.216 include direct taxation of businesses or households, 32 00:01:20.216 --> 00:01:23.613 indirect taxation with excise or consumption taxes, 33 00:01:24.870 --> 00:01:27.960 and indirect taxes can often be used 34 00:01:27.960 --> 00:01:29.850 to target health related behavioral choices, 35 00:01:29.850 --> 00:01:32.070 like lowering costs of healthy dietary options 36 00:01:32.070 --> 00:01:33.870 to encourage healthy choices, 37 00:01:33.870 --> 00:01:37.020 or conversely, by increasing costs 38 00:01:37.020 --> 00:01:38.790 of participating in health risk factors, 39 00:01:38.790 --> 00:01:43.143 like cigarette smoking or drinking alcoholic beverages. 40 00:01:46.170 --> 00:01:49.050 Next, fund pooling is another important aspect 41 00:01:49.050 --> 00:01:50.850 of healthcare financing. 42 00:01:50.850 --> 00:01:53.490 Fund pooling involves the accumulation of health revenues 43 00:01:53.490 --> 00:01:55.230 on behalf of a defined population 44 00:01:55.230 --> 00:01:58.050 for eventual transfer to providers. 45 00:01:58.050 --> 00:02:00.420 When funds are pooled, individuals are exchanging 46 00:02:00.420 --> 00:02:02.216 uncertain health related expenses 47 00:02:02.216 --> 00:02:04.680 that will occur at some point in the future 48 00:02:04.680 --> 00:02:07.053 for budgetable and predictable expenses. 49 00:02:08.370 --> 00:02:10.770 The main factors that should be considered 50 00:02:10.770 --> 00:02:14.160 when analyzing pooling arrangements are as follows. 51 00:02:14.160 --> 00:02:16.350 Number one, the size of the pool. 52 00:02:16.350 --> 00:02:18.210 Does the system have one large pool 53 00:02:18.210 --> 00:02:21.664 to cover the entire population, or separate small pools? 54 00:02:21.664 --> 00:02:24.960 Number two, the risk mix. 55 00:02:24.960 --> 00:02:27.360 What is the underlying health of the people, 56 00:02:27.360 --> 00:02:30.720 or the population whose healthcare costs are being covered? 57 00:02:30.720 --> 00:02:33.210 Does the pool, for example, include individuals 58 00:02:33.210 --> 00:02:35.130 with preexisting conditions? 59 00:02:35.130 --> 00:02:38.070 What are the demographics of the population? 60 00:02:38.070 --> 00:02:40.560 And number three, participation. 61 00:02:40.560 --> 00:02:43.980 Is participation in the pool voluntary or compulsory? 62 00:02:43.980 --> 00:02:47.850 If it's compulsory, you'll know the size of the pool. 63 00:02:47.850 --> 00:02:51.180 If it's voluntary, the size of the pool 64 00:02:51.180 --> 00:02:52.777 might not be consistent. 65 00:02:52.777 --> 00:02:57.060 You might have people joining or leaving at certain times, 66 00:02:57.060 --> 00:02:59.373 depending on personal financial situations. 67 00:03:00.960 --> 00:03:02.590 So it might be harder to predict 68 00:03:04.650 --> 00:03:09.570 financial capital that is available to the pool. 69 00:03:09.570 --> 00:03:11.640 Finally, purchasing or distribution 70 00:03:11.640 --> 00:03:13.800 involves the allocation of funds to providers 71 00:03:13.800 --> 00:03:16.350 that deliver healthcare goods or services. 72 00:03:16.350 --> 00:03:18.600 There are two primary types of purchasing: 73 00:03:18.600 --> 00:03:20.253 passive, and strategic. 74 00:03:21.360 --> 00:03:23.520 Passive purchasing transfers funds to providers 75 00:03:23.520 --> 00:03:26.493 without using information about either performance or need. 76 00:03:27.360 --> 00:03:30.450 Strategic purchasing, on the other hand, uses incentives 77 00:03:30.450 --> 00:03:33.030 and administrative mechanisms to allocate funds 78 00:03:33.030 --> 00:03:34.950 in a way that promotes quality improvement 79 00:03:34.950 --> 00:03:37.203 and efficiency of healthcare services. 80 00:03:40.020 --> 00:03:43.650 This graph displays the national healthcare expenditures 81 00:03:43.650 --> 00:03:45.480 of some major countries. 82 00:03:45.480 --> 00:03:48.270 Note that the darker shade indicates private spending, 83 00:03:48.270 --> 00:03:49.530 and the lighter shade indicates 84 00:03:49.530 --> 00:03:51.130 public or governmental spending. 85 00:03:53.412 --> 00:03:56.527 You'll also notice that some countries, 86 00:03:56.527 --> 00:04:01.527 like the United States, Canada to some extent, 87 00:04:01.950 --> 00:04:05.790 and Switzerland, have larger degrees of private spending 88 00:04:05.790 --> 00:04:08.940 on healthcare expenditures than other countries. 89 00:04:08.940 --> 00:04:10.470 You'll also notice that some countries, 90 00:04:10.470 --> 00:04:14.610 like the Czech Republic and Turkey, 91 00:04:14.610 --> 00:04:17.160 have the vast majority of their healthcare expenditures 92 00:04:17.160 --> 00:04:18.813 covered by the public sector. 93 00:04:20.400 --> 00:04:21.720 We'll be discussing this more 94 00:04:21.720 --> 00:04:23.493 as the lecturing course goes on. 95 00:04:25.500 --> 00:04:28.200 As we've discussed, there is significant variation 96 00:04:28.200 --> 00:04:30.000 in the total amount and structuring 97 00:04:30.000 --> 00:04:32.700 of healthcare expenditures between countries. 98 00:04:32.700 --> 00:04:34.110 Health expenditures are a function 99 00:04:34.110 --> 00:04:36.030 of quality of goods or services provided 100 00:04:36.030 --> 00:04:38.400 and the price of those goods and services. 101 00:04:38.400 --> 00:04:39.960 The quantity of a good or service 102 00:04:39.960 --> 00:04:41.640 is a function of the intensity, 103 00:04:41.640 --> 00:04:43.743 or how frequently an individual or group accesses 104 00:04:43.743 --> 00:04:45.990 or uses a good or service, 105 00:04:45.990 --> 00:04:48.853 and the total population size and structure. 106 00:04:48.853 --> 00:04:53.640 For example, given two countries, Country A and Country B, 107 00:04:53.640 --> 00:04:56.130 if they're both providing the same amount of services, 108 00:04:56.130 --> 00:04:59.460 for example, 1000 rapid diagnostic tests from malaria, 109 00:04:59.460 --> 00:05:00.960 but the cost in Country B 110 00:05:00.960 --> 00:05:02.853 is more than the cost in Country A, 111 00:05:03.750 --> 00:05:07.770 the health expenditures in B will be higher than A. 112 00:05:07.770 --> 00:05:10.707 Conversely, if the cost in both countries is the same, 113 00:05:10.707 --> 00:05:13.304 but Country A is providing 2000 tests 114 00:05:13.304 --> 00:05:16.090 and B is providing 1000 tests, 115 00:05:16.090 --> 00:05:19.143 then the expenditure in A will be greater than that in B. 116 00:05:20.040 --> 00:05:22.230 Variation in price and utilization intensity 117 00:05:22.230 --> 00:05:25.440 is anchored in the unique sociocultural values of nations 118 00:05:25.440 --> 00:05:27.240 and their related approaches to organizing 119 00:05:27.240 --> 00:05:28.540 and paying for healthcare. 120 00:05:30.060 --> 00:05:33.600 Governments also play a role in predicting expenditures. 121 00:05:33.600 --> 00:05:36.540 Three key metrics that they use to predict expenditures 122 00:05:36.540 --> 00:05:39.090 are health status risk, medical care risk, 123 00:05:39.090 --> 00:05:40.293 and loading factors. 124 00:05:41.280 --> 00:05:43.290 Health status risk is also sometimes called 125 00:05:43.290 --> 00:05:45.210 the "population health risk." 126 00:05:45.210 --> 00:05:47.730 That process calculating expected medical costs 127 00:05:47.730 --> 00:05:51.766 is often called the "underwriting methodology." 128 00:05:51.766 --> 00:05:55.680 Next, we turn to this graph, 129 00:05:55.680 --> 00:05:56.970 which displays government spending 130 00:05:56.970 --> 00:06:00.233 by category at 2014 levels. 131 00:06:00.233 --> 00:06:04.710 Note the differences in percentage of GDP spent on health. 132 00:06:04.710 --> 00:06:09.041 So again, health is going to be the color on the far left 133 00:06:09.041 --> 00:06:11.940 in all of these different lines, 134 00:06:11.940 --> 00:06:15.368 where the number on the far left 135 00:06:15.368 --> 00:06:19.240 is discussing the total government spending 136 00:06:19.240 --> 00:06:22.983 as a percentage of gross domestic product, or GDP. 137 00:06:24.780 --> 00:06:26.995 We see that some countries, like Denmark, 138 00:06:26.995 --> 00:06:29.346 Finland, France, Greece, 139 00:06:29.346 --> 00:06:32.250 spend more than half of their total GDP 140 00:06:32.250 --> 00:06:34.110 as government expenditure, 141 00:06:34.110 --> 00:06:36.813 whereas other countries don't spend nearly that much. 142 00:06:38.220 --> 00:06:41.310 Note too that these are all percentages, not raw numbers. 143 00:06:41.310 --> 00:06:43.734 So while one country might spend 144 00:06:43.734 --> 00:06:48.734 a lower percentage of its GDP on governmental spending 145 00:06:49.050 --> 00:06:52.260 than another country, if that country's GDP is larger, 146 00:06:52.260 --> 00:06:55.800 they may very well be spending more actual dollars 147 00:06:55.800 --> 00:06:58.893 and cents on governmental spending. 148 00:07:00.810 --> 00:07:03.189 There are two main approaches that governments take 149 00:07:03.189 --> 00:07:06.420 in regard to controlling healthcare expenditures. 150 00:07:06.420 --> 00:07:09.510 The first, the Keynesian approach, is based on the writings 151 00:07:09.510 --> 00:07:12.210 of 20th century English economist, John Maynard Keynes, 152 00:07:12.210 --> 00:07:13.560 in his School of Economics. 153 00:07:14.490 --> 00:07:16.710 This approach advocates for government intervention 154 00:07:16.710 --> 00:07:18.330 in markets to optimize outcomes 155 00:07:18.330 --> 00:07:20.070 and arrive at levels of price and intensity 156 00:07:20.070 --> 00:07:21.663 that reflect national desires. 157 00:07:22.500 --> 00:07:24.480 In contrast, the second main approach 158 00:07:24.480 --> 00:07:26.466 utilizes laissez-faire economics, 159 00:07:26.466 --> 00:07:29.040 in which markets are allowed to reach equilibrium 160 00:07:29.040 --> 00:07:32.160 in an environment with limited government intervention. 161 00:07:32.160 --> 00:07:34.260 France is an example of the Keynesian approach, 162 00:07:34.260 --> 00:07:35.700 while the United States tends to use 163 00:07:35.700 --> 00:07:37.620 the laissez-faire approach. 164 00:07:37.620 --> 00:07:40.890 Of course, most countries use a combination of the two. 165 00:07:40.890 --> 00:07:43.560 It is not an either/or choice. 166 00:07:43.560 --> 00:07:45.900 Can anyone think of an example of a Keynesian approach 167 00:07:45.900 --> 00:07:47.883 to healthcare expenditures in the US? 168 00:07:51.300 --> 00:07:53.715 For me, one of the first things that comes to mind 169 00:07:53.715 --> 00:07:55.560 is the capping of insulin costs 170 00:07:55.560 --> 00:07:58.480 at $35 per month for Medicare enrollees 171 00:08:01.620 --> 00:08:04.863 in the recently passed 2022 Inflation Reduction Act. 172 00:08:07.680 --> 00:08:10.083 This figure at first looks a little complicated. 173 00:08:10.083 --> 00:08:12.501 Hopefully will become clear. 174 00:08:12.501 --> 00:08:14.913 It's displaying a classical supply and demand curve 175 00:08:14.913 --> 00:08:18.874 to illustrate the effects of Keynesian interventions. 176 00:08:18.874 --> 00:08:23.534 Where we have price on the Y axis, 177 00:08:23.534 --> 00:08:27.450 we see that quantity is increasing on the X axis. 178 00:08:27.450 --> 00:08:32.010 So we see a line for supply and a line for demand. 179 00:08:32.010 --> 00:08:37.010 As quantity increases and the price increases, 180 00:08:37.230 --> 00:08:39.480 the supply is going to increase. 181 00:08:39.480 --> 00:08:42.705 Similarly, as demand increases, 182 00:08:42.705 --> 00:08:45.060 the price is going to increase, 183 00:08:45.060 --> 00:08:47.671 or the quantity of available goods 184 00:08:47.671 --> 00:08:49.173 is going to decrease. 185 00:08:51.142 --> 00:08:55.383 When governments implement Keynesian interventions, 186 00:08:57.549 --> 00:09:00.960 the intersection of the supply and demand curves 187 00:09:00.960 --> 00:09:05.960 can change from points D, E and F throughout the graph here. 188 00:09:06.360 --> 00:09:11.360 So for example, a government might limit the supply 189 00:09:12.385 --> 00:09:16.410 of healthcare providers, so supply would shift 190 00:09:16.410 --> 00:09:20.760 from point G on the X axis, to point H on the X axis. 191 00:09:20.760 --> 00:09:23.520 When that happens, the price of good increases, 192 00:09:23.520 --> 00:09:27.759 say for example, from B to C on the Y axis. 193 00:09:27.759 --> 00:09:30.120 The restricted supply is going to lead 194 00:09:30.120 --> 00:09:32.340 to the possibility of unmet demand. 195 00:09:32.340 --> 00:09:35.130 Individuals in situations of unmet demand 196 00:09:35.130 --> 00:09:36.938 might then be willing to pay more for services 197 00:09:36.938 --> 00:09:39.840 to have their healthcare needs or demands met. 198 00:09:39.840 --> 00:09:41.850 However, governments can also limit the price 199 00:09:41.850 --> 00:09:43.860 of healthcare services through the use of a fixed 200 00:09:43.860 --> 00:09:45.900 and centrally planned budget. 201 00:09:45.900 --> 00:09:48.390 In this case, a second constraint is introduced 202 00:09:48.390 --> 00:09:50.580 and prices are limited from drifting upward 203 00:09:50.580 --> 00:09:52.045 because the total expenses, 204 00:09:52.045 --> 00:09:54.344 the product of goods and quantity of goods, 205 00:09:54.344 --> 00:09:56.521 is set beforehand. 206 00:09:56.521 --> 00:09:58.530 In countries that use this method, 207 00:09:58.530 --> 00:10:00.690 resources can be allocated in a manner and price 208 00:10:00.690 --> 00:10:02.820 that's acceptable to most constituents. 209 00:10:02.820 --> 00:10:04.353 At point E, for example. 210 00:10:06.330 --> 00:10:09.717 Next, we'll discuss some primary healthcare models. 211 00:10:09.717 --> 00:10:11.760 Again, some of you may have heard about some of these 212 00:10:11.760 --> 00:10:13.381 in other public health courses you've taken, 213 00:10:13.381 --> 00:10:15.423 but we'll review them anyway here. 214 00:10:16.560 --> 00:10:19.140 There are four primary healthcare models we'll talk about. 215 00:10:19.140 --> 00:10:21.540 The first, universal coverage, is paid for 216 00:10:21.540 --> 00:10:24.052 through general tax revenue and covers all citizens. 217 00:10:24.052 --> 00:10:26.940 Within this model, central and regional governments 218 00:10:26.940 --> 00:10:28.680 are tasked with estimating health status 219 00:10:28.680 --> 00:10:30.960 and medical care risk for their populations, 220 00:10:30.960 --> 00:10:34.110 while simultaneously keeping costs in check. 221 00:10:34.110 --> 00:10:36.383 Most universal systems have little to no cost sharing, 222 00:10:36.383 --> 00:10:38.359 so they must employ supply side tools 223 00:10:38.359 --> 00:10:41.220 to more heavily influence healthcare infrastructure 224 00:10:41.220 --> 00:10:42.663 and overall expenses. 225 00:10:43.620 --> 00:10:45.150 Examples of countries with this model 226 00:10:45.150 --> 00:10:47.490 include the United Kingdom, Italy, 227 00:10:47.490 --> 00:10:48.783 New Zealand, and Greece. 228 00:10:49.938 --> 00:10:52.782 The second main model is social insurance, 229 00:10:52.782 --> 00:10:54.766 or the Bismarck model. 230 00:10:54.766 --> 00:10:58.560 These are also referred to as tax-based systems. 231 00:10:58.560 --> 00:10:59.550 They're heavily influenced 232 00:10:59.550 --> 00:11:01.560 by Prussian Chancellor Otto von Bismarck, 233 00:11:01.560 --> 00:11:04.020 who started a social welfare program in the 19th century 234 00:11:04.020 --> 00:11:06.540 to cover accidents, disability, and retirement 235 00:11:06.540 --> 00:11:09.000 for the Prussian working population. 236 00:11:09.000 --> 00:11:11.060 In this system, the factors of production 237 00:11:11.060 --> 00:11:13.293 can be privately or publicly owned. 238 00:11:14.340 --> 00:11:16.260 Much of Latin America, Germany, 239 00:11:16.260 --> 00:11:18.060 and Japan utilize this model, 240 00:11:18.060 --> 00:11:19.470 and their costs are mostly funded 241 00:11:19.470 --> 00:11:21.120 through employment related taxes. 242 00:11:22.320 --> 00:11:24.150 Third, national health insurance 243 00:11:24.150 --> 00:11:26.580 is a blend of the previous two models. 244 00:11:26.580 --> 00:11:28.530 Providers are independent from government, 245 00:11:28.530 --> 00:11:30.657 but receive payment from a government run insurance plan 246 00:11:30.657 --> 00:11:33.810 into which everyone is required to pay. 247 00:11:33.810 --> 00:11:35.430 Canada, South Korea, and Taiwan 248 00:11:35.430 --> 00:11:37.053 all have versions of this model. 249 00:11:38.160 --> 00:11:41.040 Fourth, private insurance, or out-of-pocket systems, 250 00:11:41.040 --> 00:11:43.800 are financed through individual or employer contributions, 251 00:11:43.800 --> 00:11:45.480 and are built upon the same foundation 252 00:11:45.480 --> 00:11:48.120 of health and medical care risk prediction. 253 00:11:48.120 --> 00:11:50.514 Private systems oftentimes exist alongside universal 254 00:11:50.514 --> 00:11:53.310 or social coverage systems to cover services 255 00:11:53.310 --> 00:11:56.520 that may not be covered by the national system. 256 00:11:56.520 --> 00:11:59.190 One version of this is the high deductible health plan, 257 00:11:59.190 --> 00:12:01.633 or the HDHP, which covers catastrophic 258 00:12:01.633 --> 00:12:04.560 or very high cost medical services, 259 00:12:04.560 --> 00:12:07.209 and are often paired with health savings accounts. 260 00:12:07.209 --> 00:12:09.900 These plans have high co-payments or deductibles, 261 00:12:09.900 --> 00:12:11.250 and expose the healthcare consumer 262 00:12:11.250 --> 00:12:14.853 to the financial consequences of behavioral choices. 263 00:12:17.100 --> 00:12:18.840 For health insurance to succeed, 264 00:12:18.840 --> 00:12:21.960 the people seeking coverage must be risk adverse, 265 00:12:21.960 --> 00:12:23.400 meaning that the insured population 266 00:12:23.400 --> 00:12:25.710 has declining marginal utility. 267 00:12:25.710 --> 00:12:27.300 The graph on the following slide 268 00:12:27.300 --> 00:12:28.900 is going to help to depict this. 269 00:12:34.110 --> 00:12:35.940 The curve in the center of this image 270 00:12:35.940 --> 00:12:38.460 is a declining marginal utility curve. 271 00:12:38.460 --> 00:12:40.230 The vertical access represents the measure 272 00:12:40.230 --> 00:12:43.680 of written individual satisfaction, or economic utility, 273 00:12:43.680 --> 00:12:47.040 and the horizontal access represents income or wealth. 274 00:12:47.040 --> 00:12:49.080 So as income increases, so does utility, 275 00:12:49.080 --> 00:12:50.970 but it does so at a declining rate. 276 00:12:50.970 --> 00:12:52.860 The relationship is nonlinear. 277 00:12:52.860 --> 00:12:54.960 More income creates more utility, 278 00:12:54.960 --> 00:12:56.760 but the impact of adding additional income 279 00:12:56.760 --> 00:13:01.443 declines in the population as it makes more money. 280 00:13:02.730 --> 00:13:04.470 In this graph, imagine that individuals 281 00:13:04.470 --> 00:13:06.390 have a 50% chance of being healthy 282 00:13:06.390 --> 00:13:08.010 and having no medical expenses, 283 00:13:08.010 --> 00:13:10.350 and a 50% chance of being sick. 284 00:13:10.350 --> 00:13:12.180 If individuals are healthy, 285 00:13:12.180 --> 00:13:15.810 they have the full $40,000 in discretionary funds. 286 00:13:15.810 --> 00:13:17.212 If sick, they incur $20,000 287 00:13:17.212 --> 00:13:20.460 in healthcare expenses and lost wages. 288 00:13:20.460 --> 00:13:21.570 Because medical expenses 289 00:13:21.570 --> 00:13:24.120 reduce discretionary income to $20,000, 290 00:13:24.120 --> 00:13:26.430 incomes who are healthy and have more discretionary income 291 00:13:26.430 --> 00:13:28.920 have a higher utility, 8,000 units, 292 00:13:28.920 --> 00:13:32.460 than those who are sick and have less income. 293 00:13:32.460 --> 00:13:36.273 Or in this chart, irons graph 4,727 units. 294 00:13:37.380 --> 00:13:39.930 As individuals cannot determine in which state of health 295 00:13:39.930 --> 00:13:41.970 they will find themselves, they cannot predict 296 00:13:41.970 --> 00:13:43.980 where they will end up on this graph. 297 00:13:43.980 --> 00:13:46.050 Insurance companies use underwriting techniques 298 00:13:46.050 --> 00:13:47.790 to estimate average medical expenses 299 00:13:47.790 --> 00:13:50.124 by calculating the probability of a person falling ill 300 00:13:50.124 --> 00:13:53.130 and the cost associated with medical care. 301 00:13:53.130 --> 00:13:54.810 Thus, by multiplying the two, 302 00:13:54.810 --> 00:13:57.450 we get an expected cost of $10,000, 303 00:13:57.450 --> 00:13:59.913 and an expected income of $30,000. 304 00:14:02.280 --> 00:14:05.354 There are two primary provider payment mechanisms. 305 00:14:05.354 --> 00:14:08.730 In the first, FFS or fee for service model, 306 00:14:08.730 --> 00:14:11.190 providers are paid on a per occurrence basis, 307 00:14:11.190 --> 00:14:14.970 and the profit incentives function are shown in this graph. 308 00:14:14.970 --> 00:14:16.290 Fixed expenses are flat, 309 00:14:16.290 --> 00:14:19.500 and variable expenses increase as services are rendered. 310 00:14:19.500 --> 00:14:22.334 At the same time, revenue depends on volume of services. 311 00:14:22.334 --> 00:14:25.650 If no services are rendered, there is no revenue. 312 00:14:25.650 --> 00:14:27.900 At low volumes, revenue is being generated, 313 00:14:27.900 --> 00:14:30.573 but does not offset the fixed and variable expenses. 314 00:14:31.440 --> 00:14:34.050 When total revenues equal total expenses, 315 00:14:34.050 --> 00:14:35.613 we reach the breakeven point. 316 00:14:37.290 --> 00:14:38.760 Finally, the pay for performance 317 00:14:38.760 --> 00:14:40.800 and value-based contracting models 318 00:14:40.800 --> 00:14:42.330 reward or penalize providers, 319 00:14:42.330 --> 00:14:45.000 based on their adherence to performance standards. 320 00:14:45.000 --> 00:14:47.610 These models are similar to the fee for service model, 321 00:14:47.610 --> 00:14:48.630 but can help to mitigate 322 00:14:48.630 --> 00:14:52.140 the potential underprovision of cases of care 323 00:14:52.140 --> 00:14:54.270 associated with fixed payment models, 324 00:14:54.270 --> 00:14:55.650 while also encouraging providers 325 00:14:55.650 --> 00:14:57.213 to deliver high quality care. 326 00:14:58.050 --> 00:15:00.453 Finally, this is a summary of what we discussed.